Friday, November 30, 2018

Observations on the Nature of Civil Liberty, Part XV: Illogical, Unthinking, Hypocritical Britain, contd.

In the third of five sections Richard Price devoted in Part II of his Observations to examining the conduct of the burgeoning conflict between Great Britain and the Thirteen Colonies – with the aim, as aforesaid, of calling said conduct into question – he proceeded to turn his attention to what he described as, “The Policy of the War with America.” His specific aim therein was essentially to establish that the stated objective of the sitting government of Lord North – i.e. to restore the previously existing relationship between Britain and its American dependencies – was exceedingly unlikely to occur in consequence of the tactics being deployed by that selfsame administration.

The analysis Price deployed to this end encompassed an admirably wide scope of contemporary foreign and domestic policy – from trade, to taxation, to banking – though the cogency of his reasoning was not always as consistent as he might have hoped. On the subject of the mercantile intercourse which had previously existed between Great Britain and its American dependencies, for example, the author of Observations keenly and effectively noted that claims made by the North Ministry to want nothing more than the resumption of harmonious trade were almost wholly at odds with the effects of the various measures that same government had endeavored to enact in the 1760s and 1770s. Similarly astute was Price’s observation that, prior to the onset of the Anglo-American crisis, Britain already enjoyed a tremendous degree of influence over almost every aspect of life and government in colonial America, and that subsequent attempts to extend this influence could not but represent a species of uncommon greed on the part of the ministry of Lord North. His accounting of Britain’s precarious monetary position was markedly less shrewd, however. Capable though Price no doubt was of comprehending and articulating the complexities of 18th century lending practices, interest rates, and currency values, his personal, ideological, and moral disdain for the luxury and corruption he believed was inevitably generated by easy access to large sums of money appeared to weigh to a greater extent upon his conclusions in this matter than did a rigorous accounting of the facts at hand. Bearing this in mind, one is rightly bound to consider to what degree the whole of Price’s defense of the ongoing America resistance to the North Ministry and its policies was spurred by a kind of spontaneous sympathy on his part to the injustices the colonists had been forced to endure, and to what extent the man was already inclined to question the virtue of any authority whose stated aim was something other than wholesale reform of Britain’s public institutions and political culture.

But let us return, for the moment, to the purpose of the North Ministry’s campaign in America. It would seem to warrant examination the degree to which Price first endeavored to make it clear at the outset of Part II, Section III that said government’s stated goal of reestablishing the accustomed supremacy of Great Britain over the colonies was an acceptable rationale only if it could be demonstrated that some form of advantage was to be thereby derived. Specifically, he explained that,

The desire of maintaining authority is warrantable, only so far as it is the means of promoting some end, and doing some good; and that, before we resolve to spread famine and fire through a country in order to make it acknowledge our authority, we ought to be assured that great advantages will arise not only to ourselves but to the country we wish to conquer.

A fairly durable rationale being thus established – that one country could justifiably assert its control over another only if it could be demonstrated that both parties stood to derive an advantage from the resulting connection – it thereby stood to reason that an inability to meet the appropriate criteria would render the relevant association – or actions taken to support it – wholly indefensible. The reason for this, Price explained, once more echoing John Locke, was that any species of authority, in order to be considered legitimate in the eyes of those who experience its power, must serve some kind of purpose outside of its own perpetuation. Governments that accordingly fail to, “Preserve the peace and to secure the safety of the state [,]” can thereby be considered, by their very nature, “Tyrannical, as far as [they constitute] a needless and wanton exercise of power [.]”

Every authority in every nation on earth was bound to measure itself by this basic standard of purpose, Britain no more or no less than any other. That Britain was the particular focus of Price’s concern and suspicion therefore owed itself – alongside that fact that Price was of course a resident of the same and a noted and longstanding critic of its institutions – to certain specific events that had recently occurred within the context of the Anglo-American crisis. First, in light of his stated conviction that, “A love of power for its own sake [is] inherent in human nature [,]” Price questioned the degree to which the British reaction against the resistance offered by the Thirteen Colonies was motivated by a regard for the law and a desire to restore some semblance of peace and security. On the contrary, he offered, “Is it not the opposition they make to our pride and not any injury they have done to us, that is the secret spring of our present animosity against them?” Had not the British people grown accustomed to looking upon the inhabitants of America as a nation, “Whom we have a right to order as we please, who hold their property at our disposal, and who have no other law than our will [?]” Price certainly believed it possible that this was the case, and wondered if certain of his countrymen might not agree if they examined their feelings on the matter more closely. “Perhaps,” he thus entreated,

They would become sensible, that it was a spirit of domination, more than a regard to the true interests of this country, that lately led so many of them, which such savage folly, to address the throne for the slaughter of their brethren in America, if they will not submit to them; and to make offers of their lives and fortunes for that purpose.

While it wouldn’t be fair to say that Price was wrong to thus question the motivations of the ministers and supporters of the government of Lord North, it nonetheless bears consideration the degree to which he could possibly have known for certain whether or not the relevant individuals were indeed acting wholly out of a sense of wounded vanity. 

The statements issued by the Crown – under the auspices of the North Ministry – in the weeks and months following the commencement of hostilities in April, 1775, while not necessarily all that kind to the leaders of the American resistance, could hardly be described as calling “for the slaughter of their brethren in America [.]” The Proclamation of Rebellion, for example, issued principally in response to the British defeat at the Battle of Bunker Hill (June 17th, 1775), went little further than referring to the instigators of the incipient colonial rebellion as, “Dangerous and ill designing men,” who had forgotten, “The allegiance which they owe to the power that has protected and supported them [.]” They were “traitorous,” to be sure, as were their “conspiracies” and their “correspondence,” and their actions most definitely constituted rebellion. But neither the king nor his government seemed yet intent on condemning anyone to slaughter. The Speech from the Throne offered in October of that same year was similarly restrained in its use of invective. The instigators of the relevant disturbance in the colonies were guilty of, “Gross misrepresentations,” it affirmed, had deployed a, “Torrent of violence” to ensure the cooperation of their fellow subjects in America, and were now engaged in a, “rebellious war […] manifestly carried on for the purpose of establishing an independent empire.” Doubtless the body of delegates then seated in the Continental Congress would have loudly and explicitly asserted that these were all of them false claims, and that describing the actions being undertaken in defense of American liberties as, “Revolt, hostility and rebellion [,]” represented nothing short of slander. But promises of a massacre, they most certainly were not.

By couching their official reaction in the language of contemporary diplomacy, law, and war, George III and his ministers had thus effectively made it that much harder to determine whether they were acting out of a sense of duty or betrayal, pragmatism or pride. To his credit – and in spite of his evident affirmation to the contrary – Price seemed to be aware of this fact, and endeavored to approach his examination of Britain’s conduct vis-à-vis the American colonies with an appropriate focus on action as well as motivation. If the policies advanced by the North Ministry – or by its recent predecessors – indeed appeared conducive to the salvation and strengthening of the Anglo-American relationship, then there would accordingly seem to be no reason at all to call the intentions of the relevant government into question. Having attempted in good faith to mend an increasingly frayed connection, whatever errors they had committed as a result could consequently have been excused and forgiven as the honest mistakes of an ultimately well-meaning administration. If, however, it might plainly be demonstrated that the actions variously pursued by successive British governments could never have resulted in the restoration and/or reinforcement of the Anglo-American relationship – or even seemed destined to do injury to the best interests of the parties involved – it would appear far from unreasonable to conclude that the purpose of said governments were something less than virtuous and pure. Having determined to wound America at the cost of wounding themselves in turn, the authorities responsible could not but be characterized as having adopted a vicious and contradictory response to having doubt cast upon the extent of their power.

Proceeding to apply this investigative framework to specific aspects of the North Ministry’s administration in America, Price first hit upon the ostensibly reckless manner in which said government had endeavored to pursue certain policies wholly and demonstrably inimical to the preservation of the already much-strained relationship between Great Britain and its American dependencies. To that end, he first set himself to enumerating the many and various pieces of legislation that had been laid by successive British governments upon either the trade of the American colonies or the revenues thereof. The Molasses Act (1733), he affirmed, was the first of these, passed in the sixth year of the reign of George II (1683-1760) with the intention – by taxing competing products – of increasing the sale in America of sugar, molasses, and the spirits derived from either that had been produced in the British West Indies. “As the act had the appearance of being only a regulation of trade,” Price was keen to note, “The colonies submitted to it [.]” Likewise did they submit to an amended version of the same legislation in 1765 – the so-called Sugar Act – though it was pursued with the express intention of, “Raising a revenue in America.” This fact, Price avowed, was cause for some alarm, “And produced discontents and remonstrances, which might have convinced our rulers that this was tender ground, on which it became them to tread very gently.” Nothing like a sustained uproar was then observed, however, for it seemed that the inhabitants of British America thought it yet still permissible for Parliament to claim the right to tax them externally. Peace was thus preserved, for the time being, though the limits of American indulgence had been nearly approached.

These limits were subsequently breached with the passage of the Stamp Act (1765). “This being,” Price affirmed,

An attempt to tax [the colonists] INTERNALLY; and a direct attack on their property, by a power which would not suffer itself to be questioned; which eased itself by loading them and to which it as impossible to fix any bounds; they were thrown at once, from one end of the continent to the other, into resistance and rage.

Vehement though the resulting public reaction most certainly was, however – ranging from hostile newspaper editorials, public demonstrations, and organized boycotts to riots that resulted in the harassment of tax officials and the destruction of public and private property – even these fervent expressions of popular discontent represented only a temporary breach of the colonists seemingly concerted intention to exercise the greatest degree possible of moderation and forbearance. Once the government of the Marquess of Rockingham (1730-1782) secured the repeal of the Stamp Act in March, 1766, the colonists showed themselves perfectly willing to ignore the implications of the accompanying Declaratory Act – the text of which stated that Parliament would continue to possess, “Full power and authority to make laws and statutes […] to bind the colonies and people of America [...] in all cases whatsoever” – and return to a state of peaceful intercourse with their fellow subjects in Britain. The colonists were perhaps not particularly encouraged by this parting shot on the part of Rockingham – this stubborn claim to hold a power which the inhabitants of British America had never consented to bestow – but as Price asserted, “They would undoubtedly have suffered us (as the people of Ireland have done) to enjoy our declaratory law.” Thus, yet again, peace was preserved.

            This was not to be the case indefinitely, of course. For whatever reason, in accordance with whatever impulse, successive British governments in the 1760s and 1770s evidently made it a common objective to continually test the limits of the Anglo-American relationship. Case in point, Price explained, “Little more than a year after the repeal of the Stamp-Act, when all was peace, a third act was passed, imposing duties payable in America on tea, paper, glass, painters colours, &c.” As one might well have expected, the result of this attempt to once more tax the colonies for the purpose of generating revenue – in the form of the so-called Townshend Duties (passed between June, 1767 and July, 1768) – was the resumption of civil demonstrations, editorial condemnation, and organized boycotts. Customs officials were once more harassed, an ultimately failed attempt was made by Massachusetts Governor Francis Bernard (1712-1779) to have certain of the instigators sent to Britain to stand trial for treason, and four British regiments were dispatched to Boston in order aid in reasserting the authority of the Crown’s various agents. Once more made conscious of the fact that efforts to tax the colonies would never be wholly frictionless, the British government – now led by the aforementioned Lord North – engineered the repeal of all but one of the odious duties, the exception being that placed on tea. While this last measure was retained, Price avowed, “In order to maintain a shew of dignity” – hardly a cause to which the beleaguered colonies would have been likely to lend their assistance – the effort nonetheless, “Answered its intended purposes.” The colonists were forced only to avoid purchasing one imported commodity instead of several, Anglo-American trade was permitted once more to recover, and customs agents were no longer to fear being chased out of their homes in the middle of the night by torch-bearing mobs. Price affirmed that this state of affairs would have remained undisturbed, “And even tea would perhaps in time have been gradually admitted, had not the evil genius of Britain stepped forth once more to embroil the Empire.”

            Granting that Price’s choice of words – i.e. “evil genius” – represented something of an overstatement, he was not necessarily wrong to suggest that the North Ministry’s actions following the repeal of the Townshend Duties were difficult to fathom if they could not be attributed to malicious intent. The desire of that government to prop up the flagging fortunes of the East India Company was understandable enough, at least. Having suffered for the loss of the American market for its tea, it was determined that the best method for encouraging a reversal of this state of affairs was for Company product to be sold in the colonies free of all taxes save for a pittance of three pence on every pound purchased. Being thus presented with the choice of going without tea altogether, purchasing illegally smuggled tea – the transportation and sale of which was the subject of continued condemnation and punishment – or purchasing the now cheap and plentiful Company tea, it was hoped that the colonists would take what was obviously the simplest path forward and begin buying what was on offer. In so doing, it was hoped that the withering fortunes of an essential institution of the British Empire might be bolstered at the same time that the inhabitants of America could be made to break their self-imposed boycott and tacitly acknowledge the right of Parliament to lay taxes on their internal commerce. While Price affirmed that this, “Snare was too gross to escape the notice of the Colonies [,]” the residents thereof nevertheless went little farther than refusing to unload the product in their ports. The exception to this otherwise peaceful refusal to cooperate in a scheme intended to trick them into surrendering an essential liberty occurred in Boston, Price allowed, wherein, “Some persons in disguise buried [the offending goods] in the sea.” And though he offered no judgment in the text of his Observations as to the righteousness or folly of this action – that being the much-mythologized Boston Tea Party of December 16th, 1773 – he did allow that the people of Massachusetts, in his opinion, would likely have been willing to make adequate compensation for the British property thereby destroyed provided that such compensation represented the whole of the punishment they were required to suffer.

            That this was not to be the case should very likely go without saying. For, in addition to the Boston Port Act – to which, Price once more asserted, “The province might possibly have submitted, and a sufficient saving would have been gained for the honor of the nation” – the North Ministry secured the passage of the aforementioned Massachusetts Government Act, the Administration of Justice Act, and the Quebec Act, all by the end of June, 1774. Combined with the four British regiments stationed in Boston following the tumults occasioned by the Townshend Duties, the people of Massachusetts were effectively left under military occupation, with no government other than that which Parliament granted them, devoid of trade with the outside world, incapable of trying certain offenders in their own courts of law, and robbed of the ability to migrate westward as their needs and their desires inclined them. All else that had been laid upon the colonies – as early as 1733 and as late as 1773 – while perhaps not likely to have enamored the inhabitants thereof to the British governments responsible, had not proven themselves beyond the ability of the American temper to endure. They had accepted the taxation of their external trade as being for the benefit of the empire at large. They had consented to a Parliamentary claim of an absolute right to tax their internal commerce so long as it was not unduly exercised. They had even managed to make their peace with the existence of a standing army in their midst over whom they could exercise not the slightest control. Now and then, in response to a policy they felt was unjust, they had certainly been willing to make their displeasure known, sometimes to the point of physical violence. But always, once the policy in question had been rescinded, they returned to their accustomed state of peaceful forbearance. Clearly, in spite of everything they had been made to suffer, these were a people willing to go to significant lengths to preserve the status quo.
                            
            Such a saintly expression of patience was not without its limits, however. Tolerant though the colonists plainly were, they had at every occasion maintained that they were under no circumstances willing to surrender the liberties to which they felt they were entitled by birth. They might have suffered to see them bent to some degree, in the name of preserving harmonious relations between themselves and their fellow subjects in Britain. But such gestures of accommodation were under no circumstances meant to give permission for further encroachments upon their basic civil rights. The popular clamor aroused by the passage of the Stamp Act in 1765 and the Townshend Duties in 1767-68 should have served as ample evidence of this essential truth. The inhabitants of British American were willing to suffer the taxation of their external trade, limited taxation of their internal trade – so long as it was relatively easy to avoid making payment – and even the deployment of armed soldiers to their streets. But they never bore any of it quietly, and, in such instances as came particularly close to forcing them to acknowledge their supposed subservience to the British government, made the nature and intensity of their discontent impossible to ignore. Such was Price’s analysis, at least. Looking back upon the aforementioned mixture of patience and conviction with which the colonists comported themselves during the 1760s and 1770s, and in light of the events of the Boston Tea Party, he affirmed in text of his Observations that,

All who knew any thing of the temper of the Colonies saw that the effect of all sudden accumulation of vengeance, would probably be not intimidating but exasperating them, and driving them into a general revolt.

The North Ministry, unfortunately, appeared truly not to know anything of the temper of the colonies. All evidence to the contrary, “They believed that the malcontents in the Colony of Massachusetts were a small party, headed by a few fractious men […] and that, the issue would prove, in a few months, order, tranquility, and submission.” Events would very quickly show otherwise.

            At this stage in his retelling of the events of 1765-1775, Price once again saw fit to call explicitly into question the sincerity of the government of Lord North in its dealings with the Thirteen Colonies. The members and supporters of that government, he affirmed, did not believe that opposition to its policies was a conviction widely held in America, or that the colonies otherwise unaffected by the events transpiring in Massachusetts would seek to make common cause with the same. Difficult as it might have been to credit an otherwise talented group of statesmen with being so exceedingly shortsighted, the fact of it was at the very least possible. That being said, once the colonies had offered their collective reaction to the passage of the aforementioned punitive acts – in the form of the Continental Congress and its America-wide non-importation agreement – these same ministers would have had no reason to any longer doubt the conviction of the offended colonists or the degree to which they were willing to actively affirm their rights. But while an honest desire to reassert the customary relationship between the colonies and the British government would seem to have required at this stage a basic reassessment of certain policies and a rededication to finding some form of accommodation, the North Ministry instead plunged stubbornly ahead.

             Having been surprised and even frightened, as Price described it, by the vehemence of the colonial reaction to the passage of the aforementioned punitive legislation, Lord North and his cabinet nevertheless refused to abandon their goal of securing the submission of British America to the absolute authority of Parliament. To that end, he affirmed,

A proposal was sent to the Colonies, called Conciliatory; and the substance of which was, that if any of them would raise such sums as should be demanded of them by taxing themselves, the Parliament would forbear to tax them.

Conciliatory though this offer was evidently intended to be, even a moment’s reflection reveals it to be anything but. The substance of it, Price declared, was something to the effect of, “If you will tax yourselves BY OUR ORDER, we will save ourselves the trouble of taxing you.” The best that such a scheme could possibly have done is save face on the part of the affected colonies by giving to them some degree of discretion as to how and from where the relevant revenue was raised. It would not have addressed the question of whether Parliament was legally entitled to make such a demand of the colonial legislatures – answered, by the colonies, emphatically in the negative – and thus could never have served to settle the disagreement at hand. The colonies, now collectively represented in the Continental Congress, accordingly rejected the proposal, and set themselves to the task of establishing the aforementioned boycott on British goods and fortifying their respective defenses in the event that armed resistance became necessary.

            Though it may seem scarcely possible to believe, Price asserted that at this point in the evolution of the Anglo-American crisis the government of Lord North made what would appear to be yet another very serious mistake. In spite of their numbers, the resources at their disposal, and their clear and demonstrated ability to engage in highly successful efforts of collective organization, the members of the North Ministry continued at this crucial moment to think of the people of Massachusetts,

As nothing but a mob, who would be soon routed and forced into obedience. It was even believed, that a few thousands of our army might march through all America, and make all quiet wherever they went. Under this conviction our ministers did not dread urging the Province of Massachusetts-Bay into rebellion, by ordering their army to seize their stores, and to take up some of their leading men.

As with every other measure that had been taken by successive British governments since 1765, aimed at securing the complete submission of the American colonies to the authority of Parliament, this attempt also resulted in failure. The people, Price avowed, took up the arms which long practice and recent preparation had readied them to use, British attempts to seize American munitions were repelled, and a British attack on a colonial position outside occupied Boston, while successful, was accomplished at an alarming cost of blood and talent. “Some of our best Generals,” Price accordingly lamented, “And the bravest of our troops, are now disgracefully and miserably imprisoned in Boston.—A horrid civil war is commenced:—And the empire is distracted and convulsed.” There would seem to have been, by Price’s reckoning, only one explanation as to how this turn of events could possibly have come to pass.

It could not have been commerce, for the colonies had long-since shown themselves perfectly willing to render up any number of commercial advantages upon request by Parliament and the Crown. “They gave up the power of making sumptuary laws,” Price thus affirmed, “And exposed themselves to all the evils of an increasing and wasteful luxury, because we were benefited by vending among them the materials of it.” In light of the degree to which the original Puritan founders of the Massachusetts Bay Colony and the Plymouth Colony strove to create societies purged of sin by enacting legal restrictions upon what a person could wear, what kinds of games they could play, and whether they could smoke tobacco or drink alcohol, this would indeed seem to represent a significance concession on their part to the mercantile interests of Great Britain and its traders. Just so, Price continued, “The iron with which providence had blessed their country, they were required by laws, in which they acquiesced, to transport hither, that our people might be maintained by working it for them into nails, ploughs, axes, &c.” As it happened, the terms of the Iron Act (1750) had indeed placed fairly unequivocal restrictions on the ability of interested colonial entrepreneurs to erect any more iron works than already existed, thus conveying a definite advantage upon such British manufacturers as were now able to purchase duty-free pig-iron from the colonies, use the resulting savings to expand their operations, and flood the America market with cheap wrought iron and refined steel.

            Granted, there was more to both of these scenarios that Price seemed willing to admit. While it was certainly to the benefit of British industry – particularly in the realms of luxury textiles, distilling, and artisan metalwork – for the New England Puritan to abandon their various socio-legal prohibitions against personal indulgence, the relevant movement away from strict sumptuary proscriptions did not come solely at the behest of contemporary British governments. Eager though British merchants most definitely were to obtain greater access to American consumers, and strict though the Puritan-dominated governments in New England generally remained in their respective interpretations of what was permissible and what was forbidden, the truth of the matter is that within a few decades of the start of the colonial project, enough residents of the relevant colonies had taken to defying the sumptuary laws that they ceased to be actively enforced. It may be said, therefore, that while British traders naturally wasted no time in seizing upon the opportunity to sell their wares in this previously much-restricted market – thus accomplishing the further integration of New England into the larger imperial economy – neither they nor their sponsors in government created the opportunity itself. By the same token, while the Iron Act did seek to create a set of circumstances by which it was almost certainly cheaper to purchase finished iron and steel products from British manufacturers than from the few American refineries that were permitted to exist, the fact of the legislation itself tells only half the tale. As with the earlier Molasses Act (1733) and the subsequent duties upon tea, colonial Americans were perfectly willing and able to accept the passage of a restrictive commercial law like the Iron Act in public while taking such measures as were necessary to evade its terms in private. As Parliament yet still lacked sufficient means to police the enforcement of most any of its colonial policies, iron refineries and forges remained quite common in contemporary British America, particularly in such cases as their owners and operators were members of the socio-political elite in colonies like Maryland and Virginia.

            Despite his somewhat one-sided representation of the character of the Anglo-American relationship – i.e. the colonies bending over backwards to be accommodating to the vast majority of Britain’s desires and priorities – Price was nevertheless correct to assert that, prior to the middle 1760s, the American colonies had shown themselves quite willing to accept their place as an appendage of the larger British Empire. Privately, certain residents thereof might have questioned the wisdom or the necessity of certain policies or statutes, even to the point of taking steps to actively evade them. But they evidently did not feel inclined to call into question the legality of such measures as the Molasses Act or the Iron Act. Parliament, they evidently concluded, was within its rights to attempt to regulate the economy of the British Empire as a whole, and to take such action to that end, vis-à-vis the American colonies, as appeared to be necessary. That the colonists themselves freely purchased British products – from the metalwork prejudiced by the terms of the Iron Act to the luxury goods at one time prohibited by law in the Puritan jurisdictions of Massachusetts and Plymouth – arguably served to ratify their acceptance of this basic arrangement. Indeed, Price affirmed,

By purchasing our goods they paid our taxes; and, by allowing us to regulate their trade in any manner we thought most for our advantage, they enriched our merchants, and helped up to bear our growing burdens. They fought our battles with us. They gloried in their relation to us. All their gains centered among us; and they always spoke of this country and looked to it as their home. 
                       
Though, again, the author of Observations seemed inclined to portray the inhabitants of British America as inherently – some might say excessively – inclined to embrace their status as the distant province of a large and magnificent empire, his core observation remained a valid one.

The colonists had rarely question Britain’s authority, and never effectively threatened it. The British economy, in consequence, had reaped tremendous advantages by its connection with America, and successive governments had been able to oversee periods of growth, prosperity, and even military success as a result. The North Ministry’s campaign, between 1765 and 1775, to further bind the various colonial governments to the will and authority of Parliament could not, therefore, had had anything to do with an unwillingness on the part of the colonists to continue playing their accustomed role as loyal and active subjects of the British Crown. Rather, Price affirmed, it could only have been the result of a senseless, needless, and ultimately destructive need for a greater and greater degree of control. Thus did he write that the British government and people,

Not contended with a degree of power, sufficient to satisfy any reasonable ambition […] have attempted to extend it.—Not contended with drawing from [the colonies] a large revenue indirectly, we have endeavoured to procure one directly by an authoritative seizure; and, in order to gain a pepper-corn in this way, have chosen to hazard millions, acquired by the peaceable intercourse of trade.

The result of such a “Vile policy [,]” Price vehemently asserted, could not be anything but disastrous.

Having come to depend, increasingly, upon the produce and purchasing power of the American colonies, the North Ministry had nevertheless taken such actions as effectively placed precisely these resources beyond the reach of the British state. If the cabal in question had only been contended – had they recognized that what they stood to gain by attempting to bind the colonial governments more closely to the will of Parliament was by no means worth the acrimony that was bound to result – this might not have been the case. They were not contended, of course, and the result was the effective destruction of the goodwill and amity that had substantially persisted between the people and government of Great Britain and their respective counterparts in British America. Indeed, as Price took to characterizing the matter, “Their love is turned into hatred; and their respect for our government into resentment and abhorrence.” And yet, while it would seem exceedingly difficult to somehow reverse this turn of events, it might not have been impossible to do so. Driven by greed and arrogance though the North Ministry arguably had been in its pursuit of greater and greater control over the economies and governments of the various American colonies, it would not have been impossible for them to cease their ill-conceived campaign of domination in the name of restoring that which they had previously endeavored to destroy. All that would have been necessary – injurious to the pride of Lord North and his cabinet though it may well have been – was for the sitting government to request a halt to armed hostilities, petition the Continental Congress for a formal redress of grievances, and approach the resulting negotiations in the spirit of reason, liberality, and good faith. Only then might the actions of the British government have finally matched its rhetoric.

Price was not so naïve as to imagine that this was a particularly likely outcome, of course. If the North Ministry really did desire nothing more than to pursue a program of reform to the Anglo-American relationship without necessarily threatening its integrity – or even if its members had originally sought something more than that but were willing to admit that they had been mistaken – Lord North himself could have (and perhaps should have) called for a ceasefire at any number of opportunities. When news of the first shots having been fired in anger at the Battles of Lexington and Concord arrived in London, for example, he would doubtless have been forgiven by many of his supporters for deciding that it represented the better part of prudence to pull back from the brink. The costly Battle of Bunker Hill would seem to have represented much the same kind of occasion, or the beginning of the Siege of Boston, or the American invasion of British Quebec. That the North Ministry chose not to avail itself of these chances, however, and that it instead determined with even greater vehemence to achieve the armed pacification of America, seemed to affirm Price’s steadfast belief that it was a lust for power rather than any need for closer commercial ties that had motivated and continued to motivate the sitting government of Great Britain.

Far from emerging from their defeat at the hands of British arms wielded by British hands eager and able to offer the victorious government even greater access to their resources and markets, Price in fact asserted that,

The provinces of America, when desolated, will afford no revenue; or if it should, the expence of subduing them and keeping them in subjection will much exceed that revenue.—Not any of the advantages of trade: For it is folly, next to insanity, to think trade can be promoted by impoverishing our customers, and fixing in their minds an everlasting abhorrence of us.

No doubt Price would have said that this was a fairly obvious conclusion to draw. War does not often turn enemies into capable and enthusiastic business partners. That Lord North and his supporters appeared neither to understand this maxim nor heed it thus appeared to demonstrate that the needs of business were not and had never been their concern. Far from seeking, as they claimed, merely to affirm the proper place of the American colonies within the larger context of Britain’s global financial empire, they rather endeavored to gratify their collective ego and sooth their wounded pride by forcing the complete subjugation of that distant population who dared to assert that their liberties were beyond the power of Parliament to affect.

No comments:

Post a Comment