Friday, February 27, 2015

Corporations in the Early United States, Part II: Hamilton, Jefferson and the Bank of the United States

As I recall I've mentioned previously, the financial situation in the United States during the years of the Revolution and its immediate aftermath was more than a little precarious. In the interest of providing a bit more depth on certain topics, a brief overview of the American experience with banking in general up until 1790 will follow.

 In order to purchase supplies abroad the Continental Congress was forced to borrow millions of dollars from its European allies (France and the Netherlands chief among them) while at the same time possessing no obvious mechanism to repay the debts that resulted. At the same time domestic costs were paid for by the issuance of Continental Currency, a type of paper bill printed on the authority of Congress and totalling, by the end of the war, almost $250 million. Unfortunately, because Congress wasn't able to control the supply of money by either taxing it or selling bonds, the value of the Continentals depreciated rapidly. This loss of value was aided by the fact that the states themselves issued bills of credit in their own names, and by successful British attempts to counterfeit the Continentals and pass them into circulation from their headquarters in occupied New York City. By the end of 1778, three years after their first issue, the Continentals had lost all but 1/5 of their value; by 1780 they’d sunk to 1/40.

In 1782 an attempt to remedy the situation materialized in the form of the Bank of North America. The brainchild of Superintendent of Finance Robert Morris and his ally and confidant Alexander Hamilton, the purpose of the bank was to help fund the war effort by establishing a stable national currency in the United States. The bills of credit issued by the bank were to be backed by a public offering of 1000 shares at $400 each. In addition to those purchases made by private citizens, most of the shares were paid for by Morris with hard currency either loaned from France and the Netherlands or contributed from his own personal fortune. The paper currency that was issued by the bank as a result was then permitted to be used as payment for taxes owed to either the federal government or many of the state governments. This created a mechanism of control over the money supply in order to prevent the runaway inflation that had plagued the Continentals. Unfortunately the Bank of North America operated under a distinct set of limitations that prevented it from becoming the national institution its federal charter envisioned. For one, it didn't operate in more than a handful of states. Controversy over the legality of Congress incorporating a national bank led to the BNA seeking charters from the states instead. Subsequently in its day-to-day operations the Bank of North America operated more like a commercial bank that happened to be headquartered in Philadelphia. This tendency was amplified by Morris’ dominant role as the institution’s chief financial backer. In an effort to prevent inflation Morris recommended that Bank of North America notes should not be used in private transactions, and in high risk situations even took to issuing bills of credit backed by his own fortune rather allow potential harm to come to befall the bank’s credit. Public use of BNA notes was thus far more limited than originally intended. When the Revolutionary War concluded in 1783 Congress removed its deposits and the Bank of North America reverted to the status of a Pennsylvania-chartered state bank, which in many ways it had always been.

While the Bank of North America succeeded in securing some much-needed funding for the American war effort during the latter years of the Revolution, it failed to alleviate the financial woes that plagued many of the states. Congress as well as the various state governments remained severely in debt, and because of the weaknesses inherent in the Articles of Confederation there existed no way for the federal government to reliably collect taxes in order to pay off its obligations. At the same time, the limited scope within which the Bank of North America operated ensured that most Americans continued to be unfamiliar with the fundamental principles behind banking and the day-to-day realities of how such financial institutions operated. Unlike in Great Britain, where in the 18th century a multitude of private and county banks flourished, people living and working in the United States in the 1770s and 1780s existed in a world where, in addition to coined metal, private wealth was the basis of most transactions. Between merchants, bills of credit were often issued in exchange for goods or services rendered with the understanding that they would be paid at a set date. These bills could be passed on to others as payment for additional goods or services, and in essence functioned as a form of paper money. Those individuals who had accrued large sums of money over the course of their career likewise provided most of the loan capital and subsisted on the accumulated interest. Banking in the European tradition, as facilitated by a mix of private and public corporations, only became necessary in the United States during the Revolutionary War with the need to very quickly raise very large sums of money.

As the delicate economic situation of the United States had been a chief motivator for the calling of the Philadelphia Convention of 1787 and the drafting of a new federal constitution, providing a remedy was among the first major efforts the newly-formed government attempted. Alexander Hamilton, delegate to the Philadelphia Convention from New York and Robert Morris’s erstwhile collaborator, was appointed the first Secretary of the Treasury in 1789 and very quickly brought to the attention of Congress a set of linked proposals he believed would stabilize the economic prospects of the United States. Among the measures he suggested, in his Second Report on Public Credit, was the incorporation of a national bank.

For the record, nowhere in the United States Constitution are the words “bank,” “charter” or “incorporate” utilized. Indeed, the very concept of Congress or any other branch of the federal government possessing a right to issue charters of incorporation is entirely absent. This became an issue for those who considered themselves strict constructionists, believing that that meaning of the Constitution was best determined by as plain a reading of the text as possible. Thomas Jefferson, then Secretary of State, was chief among them, and pointed out at length that the incorporation of a national bank was fundamentally beyond the remit of Congress. Many present at the Philadelphia Convention, however, likely took it for granted that the power of a governmental body to issue such charters was among the standard legislative repertoire that had been established during the colonial era. That the government framed by the Constitution, about as robust as most Americans had ever seen, would lack such a basic legal prerogative would doubtless have seemed strange to some. To this it should be added that the Constitution explicitly states that Congress possesses the right to, “borrow Money on the credit of the United States,” “coin Money, regulate the Value thereof, and of foreign Coin,” and, “provide for the Punishment of counterfeiting the Securities and current Coin of the United States.” While Jefferson claimed that the Treasury Department could have accomplished these things without the need for a national bank, Hamilton and his supporters once more drew on the Necessary and Proper Clause for validation. This sentence at the end of Article I, Section 8 states that, in addition to all of the rights already declared, Congress also has the ability, “To make all Laws which shall be necessary and proper for carrying into Execution the foregoing Powers and all other Powers vested by this Constitution in the Government of the United States, or in any Department or Officer thereof.” A national bank, Hamilton argued, was necessary (“needful, requisite, incidental, useful, or conductive”) to the accomplishment of the stated aims, and was at the same time not strictly prohibited by the text of the Constitution.

 On their own, Hamilton’s arguments in favour of a national bank are numerous, and in all likelihood could be collected into a not insubstantial volume. That being the case, and the theme of this series being specifically the opinions expressed by the Founders vis-à-vis corporations, I’ll restrict the spotlight I choose to shine to those contentions that I feel touch upon that topic. In that spirit I turn first to the aforementioned Second Report on Public Credit.  

 The first of three reports delivered to Congress concerning the economic prospects of the newly formed United States government, Hamilton’s Second Report was presented to that legislative body in December, 1790. A lengthy and well-argued document, befitting the meticulous Hamilton, it argued strongly in favor of the formation of a national bank on the grounds that, among other things, it would increase the productive capital of the United States, decrease incidents of various financial calamities, and strengthen the federal government by making it easier to collect tax revenues and receive foreign loans. Amidst the various points that Hamilton brought to bear was the common refrain that a national bank was a public entity whose primary beneficiaries would be, directly or indirectly, the citizens of the United States. The institution that Hamilton proposed was not just another commercial bank, of which the United States possessed a good number already, but a “national bank,” or “public bank,” that would become a “nursery of national wealth,” render financial assistance to the federal government in times of emergency, and facilitate the payment of federal taxes by making loans available for that purpose. He made no secret of the fact that it was a species of corporation he was promoting, and went into significant detail describing the sale of shares, the circumstances of annual shareholder meetings and the distribution of dividends, but the greatest benefits he seemed keen to reserve to the United States government and the American public.

The capital of the national bank, meaning the sum total of currency it would be entitled to loan out as a factor of the total amount of hard currency it possessed, was one of the things which critics of the proposal believed was most rife for abuse. Paper money printed in excess without being backed by a form of stable, material wealth (in the 18th century, gold and/or silver), they argued, could lead to rapid devaluation, rampant speculation, and general economic calamity. Hamilton’s Second Report responded to this claim by once more pointing to the degree of public accountability under which the proposed national bank would function. It would be the domain of the legislature that created the bank, he stated, to set or adjust the limit of its capital in such a way as to both facilitate the expansion of business and trade as well as provide for the security of the public. Another criticism levelled at the model Hamilton proposed was the degree to which it would allow foreigners to purchase shares of the bank and thereby benefit from or influence the financial affairs of a country not their own. Admitting that foreigners would be entitled to both own bank stock and collect half-yearly dividends as a result, Hamilton asserted in his Second Report that the benefits these alien investors brought with them would be far in excess of what they might potentially extract. Purchases of bank shares by any source would bring in hard currency (again, gold and silver) that would serve to increase or at least solidify the institution’s existing capital; this capital in turn would be at the behest of American citizens whose economic activities directly enhance the overall wealth of the United States. While in either case, concerning overall capital or foreign investors, there existed the potential for abuse Hamilton believed this was hardly reason for outright disapproval. “If the abuses of a beneficial thing are to determine its condemnation,” he wrote, “there is scarcely a source of public prosperity which will not speedily be closed.” Though a national bank would inevitably benefit certain individuals more than others, and even generate a degree of harm if improperly managed, to Hamilton it was still a source of, “general profit and advantage.” The American public, he seemed keen to point out, would still exercise control over certain aspects of the proposed bank, and would draw the greatest share of the advantages it promised. 

The number of times that Hamilton returned to this chorus, of public oversight and public benefit, in his proposal for a national bank would seem to indicate that his conception of the purpose of at least some kinds of corporations was based on the concept of public utility. A national bank, he wrote, would protect merchants from unforeseen economic shocks (by providing credit), increase the quantity of hard currency in the United States (by facilitating foreign trade), and stamp out the speculation and financial instability of the post-Revolutionary era. Amidst these claims there was little talk of customers, private property or shareholders and a great deal of public good, public accommodation and the, “security of the community.” Though again Hamilton made no effort to obscure the fact that the proposed bank would be privately administered and financed by primarily private capital, he stated with equal candor that, “public utility is more truly the object of public banks than private profit. And it is the business of Government to constitute them on such principles, that, while the latter will result in a sufficient degree to afford competent motives to engage in them, the former be not made subservient to it.” Accepting the fact that Hamilton may have simply been phrasing his proposal just so as to assuage the fears of those who were unfamiliar with banking or felt the practice was inherently corrupt, it would at least appear that his take on the mixed public/private corporation that is the national bank leaned heavily in the direction of the public aspects.

From where Hamilton derived his particular conception of national banks, and perhaps of nationally-chartered corporations in general, is also evident in his Second Report. Near the end of his lengthy proposal, after explaining the utility of allowing the bank to accept United States public debt as payment for bank shares, Hamilton saw fit to put forth an example of a similar national institution which functioned successfully on the same grounds. Specifically he referred to the Bank of England, chief financial institution of the Government of Great Britain. Like the proposed Bank of the United States, the Bank of England was a privately owned corporation (charted in 1694) that provided government access to credit and issued bank notes. The very existence of the Bank of England, Hamilton was keen to point out, was based on a loan to the British government and the resulting debt (£1,200,000). That this same institution, in the decades that followed, was able to augment its capital to something on the order of £12,000,000 while at the same time helping to propel Great Britain to the status of unequivocal world power was doubtless considered by the Treasury Secretary as a mark in its favour, and cause for emulation. This unabashed praise of the Bank of England by Hamilton would seem to be the most revealing of all the argument he put forth in his Second Report. While most Americans in the 1770s and 1780s would have been at least somewhat familiar with the type of corporations that had typically been chartered during the colonial era in order to provide building or maintenance services, they might only have had limited knowledge of the more complex, explicitly profit-driven corporate institutions that were the mainstay of European empire, such as national banks or trading companies. Hamilton was doubtless familiar with both, but it was the latter that were most essential to his vision of the potential and prosperity of the United States of America.

Though they had doubtless facilitated their share of abuses, and would go on to do so, the Bank of England or the British East India Company were primarily sources of wealth, prestige, and power for Great Britain during the 17th, 18th and 19th centuries. By allowing the personal wealth of their shareholders to primarily finance their activities they allowed Britain to expand its economy and trade network at a relatively low cost to the government and the average British taxpayer. Hamilton, it seemed, envisioned something similar for the United States; the use of private resources backed by government approval, used to accomplish public ends. While some might have questioned the propriety of placing control of national monetary policy in private hands, or giving what was essentially carte blanche to a group of independently-minded entrepreneurs, Hamilton likely saw the utility of nationally-charted corporations as being rather obvious. Something of an anglophile – a fact which often played to his detriment – his estimation of the surest path for the United States to pursue toward power and prestige on the world stage was very much rooted in the model set by Great Britain during the 17th and 18th centuries. At the core of this model was the creating and expansion of a national banking system along with a stable currency. At the same time there was also inherent in the United States Constitution, which had recently been adopted and which Hamilton had a hand in shaping, a realist and utilitarian approach to some of the less flattering aspects of human nature. Just as the notion of creating a strict separation of powers was an attempt to channel personal ambition in such a way as to ensure that no one branch of government was able to dominate the others, the chartering of corporations on the British model was a means of utilizing the inherently avaricious qualities of capitalism for the benefit of the public.

Though he was but one of the many prominent individuals whose efforts shaped and guided the direction of the United States during its early decades, Alexander Hamilton was in many ways the exemplar of a highly influential intellectual strain of American nationalism. An arch-Federalist, realist, utilitarian and anglophile, Hamilton believed in strong central government, regarded manufacturing and other mercantile interests as the key to sustainable economic growth, and saw corporations as essential tools in achieving both of these ends. Certainly, he granted, the shareholders of these corporate entities stood to profit to a greater extent than the average citizen, and may even abuse the privileges granted them via incorporation, but this was hardly cause to abandon the scheme altogether. Public good was public good; so long as a corporation served that end, be it by issuing paper currency, distributing loans, conducting foreign trade or building a bridge, it fulfilled its purpose and justified its existence. If it did not; if its net benefit to society at large was negligible and a grant of corporate privilege would only serve to enrich private wealth further, then no such grant was called for. It was not a perfect arrangement – Hamilton being a man who seemingly did not believe in perfection – but its success was proven by experience.   
Mr. Jefferson, as was so often the case, did not agree.

No comments:

Post a Comment