The 16th Amendment would seem to among the most commonly overlooked of its brethren. It was the final amendment to be drafted before the state legislatures lost their access to the drafting process itself, which makes it highly significant to the discussion currently underway in these pages. But its object is not what one might particularly call thrilling. The text of it reads, in full:
The Congress shall have power to lay
and collect taxes on incomes, from whatever source derived, without
apportionment among the several States, and without regard to any census or
enumeration.
Again, hardly
thrilling. Indeed, quite mundane. And yet, the 16th Amendment has
proven to be exceptionally consequential. It is a product of its era, to be
sure, being the brainchild of populism and imperialism in more or less equal
measure. But beyond its particular historical significance, it also inarguably
forms the cornerstone of the funding regime underpinning the modern American
republic. Without the ability to collect taxes on personal incomes “without
regard to any census or enumeration,” the United States Government would not be
able to borrow the increasingly large sums of money which have come to
constitute one of its primary sources of revenue and it would accordingly have
been unable to fund most of the initiatives it has undertaken over the course
of the last century. Without the 16th Amendment, in short, the
American republic would be but a shadow of the global power which the modern
world has come to know. Say about this what you will – whether you believe a
globally dominant United States is good for the world or not – but the
historical significance of the thing would seem next to impossible to deny.
Bearing this in mind, it would accordingly appear to be a line of inquiry worth
pursuing precisely how the amendment itself came about. Who favored it, and
why, and what did they ultimately hope to achieve?
In order to answer these questions –
and in order to satisfy the broader purpose of the inquiry currently underway –
we must return once more to the so-called “Progressive Era” of American
politics. Or rather, we must return to the Progressive Era…eventually. The
amendment itself, after all, was approved by Congress in the summer of 1909 and
was ratified by the requisite number of states at the beginning of 1913. But
the story of how the whole initiative came about actually extends back at least
as early as the 1860s. During the Civil War, it seems, in order to fund what
would soon prove to be a truly gargantuan war effort, Congress passed the first
of what would soon become several federal Revenue Acts. Introduced at various
points between 1861 and 1865, these acts initially levied and then increased
the first federal income tax in the history of the American republic, the
proceeds of which would at their height account for approximately one-fifth of
the annual federal revenue. Intended to compensate for increased personal
investment in stocks as opposed to property – the latter of which the federal
government had been freely taxing for decades – the levy took the form of a
simple flax tax – three percent, initially – on personal incomes in excess of
eight hundred dollars. As an emergency measure needed to see the nation through
a disastrous and unprecedented war, the American people were evidently willing
to tolerate such an intrusion into their personal financial affairs. And at
length, by way of the Springer v. United States decision in 1881, the
Supreme Court came around to acknowledging the measure as being in keeping with
the Constitution. But none of this meant that income tax was going to continue
to be collected indefinitely. By the time the Revenue Act of 1864 came time to
be renewed in the early 1870s, Congress declined to do so on the grounds that such
levies were no longer necessary. The war was over, the state of emergency had
passed, and there just didn’t seem to be any cause for the federal government
to continue collecting more than the standard mix of tariffs and property
taxes.
Enter, twenty years later, the administration of Grover Cleveland (1837-1908), the first Democrat elected to the office of President since 1856. Cleveland and his allies had made a general lowering of tariffs a major campaign promise during the leadup to the Election of 1892, and once in office proceeded to follow through on their pledge with the drafting of a major tariff bill in 1894. As the intended reduction in taxes upon raw materials would have also, in isolation, resulted in a reduction in federal revenues, however, certain among the Democrats who then controlled Congress sought to compensate by additionally levying a relatively modest federal income tax. This would constitute the first federal income tax in two decades, it was true, and the first ever to be collected outside of a period of national emergency. But in practical terms, on a per capita basis, it was substantially less onerous than its Civil War-era predecessors. Applying only to incomes in excess of four thousand dollars – and including dividends, gifts, and inheritances – the federal government would collect a mere two percent for itself. Not every Democrat within the contemporary party caucus was necessarily in favor of this attempt to balance the federal books, it bears noting. Indeed, many of them were far more concerned with simply lowering the tariffs and were willing to tolerate the corresponding tax increases – foisted upon them by populist Congressmen William Jennings Bryan (1860-1925) and Benton McMillin (1845-1933) – only because they suspected that the Supreme Court would strike them down. This, as it happened, is just what the Supreme Court ultimately did.
Following the passage of the resulting Wilson-Gorman Tariff Act in 1894 – so named for its co-sponsors, Congressman William Wilson (1843-1900) and Senator Arthur Gorman (1839-1906) – a New York-based bank called the Farmers’ Loan & Trust Company determined to comply with the act on behalf of its various shareholders. Not only were the bank’s directors intent on delivering the applicable percentages to the Department of the Treasury, but they also intended to provide to this same body the names of every individual whose income was thus being taxed. Among these individuals, a man named Charles Pollack then raised an objection. Though he owned, in total, only ten shares in the bank, he did not want them unilaterally disposing of any portion of his income. Accordingly, he brought suit. And while his case was initially dismissed when it found its way into the federal circuit courts, Pollack then appealed to the Supreme Court, which delivered its ruling in the spring of 1895. The substance of the opinion, as written by Chief Justice Melville Fuller (1833-1910), was that while taxes on incomes alone were perfectly permissible under the terms of the Constitution – in keeping with the Court’s aforementioned Springer v. United States decision – taxes on incomes derived from dividends, rents, or interest decidedly were not. The reason for this, as Chief Justice Fuller explained it, was that an income derived from the ownership of a type of property – be it a piece of land, a building, or a share of stock – could not be legally separated from the property itself. Income derived from property, after all, was but an extension of whatever value that the property in question may have held. Taxes on property income were therefore tantamount to direct taxes, which, according to Article I, Section 2 of the Constitution, “Shall be apportioned among the several States which may be included within this Union, according to their respective Numbers [.]” While all other types of incomes could be taxed in the form of an excise, therefore, incomes derived from property had to be treated like property. The relevant portion of the Wilson-Gorman Act was therefore null and void.
The Pollock v. Farmers' Loan & Trust Company (1895) decision did not turn out to be a particularly popular one among large swaths of the contemporary American political class. Indeed, at a time when members of both parties were increasingly concerned with things like inefficiency, waste, corruption, wealth inequality, and the rise of corporate monopolies, Chief Justice Fuller’s ruling that the primary incomes of some of the nation’s wealthiest citizens were practically immune from taxation did not land very well at all. The Democratic Party, for one, had become increasingly intertwined with the contemporary populist movement, the primary supporters of which were agrarian westerners who felt that an overreliance on tariffs would only end up punishing poor farmers and laborers. The industrialized East was where most of the nation’s wealth was concentrated, and yet it was the comparatively impoverished South and West where people would end up sacrificing a larger portion of their incomes in paying taxes on the goods they needed to survive. The Democrats accordingly made a meal out of the Pollack ruling, going so far as to include a federal income tax plank in their platform leading up to the Election of 1896 and choosing the aforementioned William Jennings Bryan as their nominee for President.
Many progressive Republicans were also mightily displeased at the outcome of the Pollack case, though the nature of their disapproval had its roots in a different source. Whereas populist Democrats were concerned primarily with wealth inequality, Republicans like Robert La Follette (1855-1925), Theodore Roosevelt (1858-1919), and Norris Brown (1863-1960) saw the era’s increasingly large and powerful corporations as representing the single greatest threat to the prosperity of the American citizen. So long as these entities were permitted to continue growing unchecked, these men avowed, they would eventually form monopolies which no force on Earth could counter and whose primary victims would be the consumers forced to pay whatever rates their corporate overlords set. By disallowing the taxation of things like dividends and interest – absent a practically unworkable scheme of state-by-state apportionment – Pollack effectively helped to aid this process along by allowing corporations to drain more wealth out of the country than they could ever pay back in tariffs. But while Republican lawyers and statesmen began notching out victories in the states against various species of corporation – see La Follette’s battles with the railroads during his tenure as Governor of Wisconsin and Roosevelt’s support for the Ford Franchise-Tax Bill (1899) as Governor of New York – similar success at the federal level continued to elude them in the wake of the Pollack ruling. As long as Chief Justice Fuller’s decision was still the last word on taxing property incomes, there seemed to be no point in even broaching the subject in Congress.
Events finally took a significant turn in favor of reform in the spring of 1909 following the inauguration as President of Republican William Howard Taft (1857-1930). In a special message to Congress in July of that year, Taft drew attention to the Pollack decision, what he perceived to be its negative impact on domestic tax policy, and the need for some manner of remediation. “The decision of the Supreme Court in the income-tax cases,” he notably declared,
Deprived the National Government of a
power which, by reason of previous decisions of the court, it was generally
supposed that Government had. It is undoubtedly a power the National Government
ought to have. It might be indispensable to the nation's life in great crises.
Although I have not considered a constitutional amendment as necessary to the
exercise of certain phases of this power, a mature consideration has satisfied
me that an amendment is the only proper course for its establishment to its
full extent. I therefore recommend to the Congress that both Houses, by a
two-thirds vote, shall propose an amendment to the Constitution conferring the
power to levy an income tax upon the National Government without apportionment
among the States in proportion to population.
Unsurprisingly, this
call for an income tax amendment by the leader of their party roused many
progressive Republicans to begin pursuing exactly that. Ultimately, it was the
aforementioned Senator Brown who succeeded in drafting the requested reform. But
its successful passage through Congress was only made possible by a major split
then threatening to tear the Republican Party apart.
Taft’s message, it bears noting, had been
delivered at a time when his party both held the majority in both houses of
Congress and was also in the midst of a rather punishing debate about federal
tariffs. Progressive Republicans like Senators Norris and La Follette were for
their part favor of lowering most tariffs, as were populist Democrats from the
South and West. Tariffs, they all agreed, disproportionally impacted the
poorest members of American society while raising far less in federal revenues
than other kinds of taxes might. Conservative Republicans, meanwhile, held
protectionism to be a core tenet of the Republican Party gospel. As explained
by men like Nelson Aldrich (1841-1915), majority leader and chairman of the
Senate Finance Committee, tariffs protected the profits of American business,
ensured high wages for industrial workers, and prevented American farmers from
being undercut by foreign competition. In the immediate, given this division,
there did not seem to be much hope for compromise. When Republican Congressmen
Sereno Payne (1843-1914) put forth an initial proposal that would have seen
tariffs lowered across the board, Senator Aldrich offered a counterproposal that
would have lowered fewer tariffs and actively increased several more.
Progressives then responded with a proposal straight out of Taft’s address. It
was the duty of the those who aimed to lower federal tariffs, he said, in light
of what he described as the “rapidly increasing deficit […] to arrange the duty
so as to secure an adequate income, and […] that if it was not possible to do
so by import duties, new kinds of taxation must be adopted [.]” A tax on
inheritances was Taft’s first choice, but as this seemed to be something of a
non-starter with Senate Republicans, he was instead inclined to suggest, “An
amendment to the tariff bill imposing upon all corporations and joint stock
companies for profit […] an excise tax measured by 2 per cent on the net income
of such corporations.” Not only would this serve as, “An excise tax upon the
privilege of doing business as an artificial entity” but it was calculated to,
“Bring into the Treasury of the United States not less than $25,000,000.” With
a newly inaugurated President thus urging them on, progressive Republicans
accordingly inserted just such an amendment into the tariff bill.
It was at this point that Senator Aldrich
attempted a little slight-of-hand. With the Republican caucus thus split and
his leadership in the Senate under threat, he decided to offer his progressive
opponents something on the order of a trade. In exchange for their support of
his version of the tariff bill – with included more increases than decreases as
well as a tax on corporate incomes – he was willing to throw his own weight
behind the draft income tax amendment that Senator Brown was attempting to
promote. In actual fact, he was not in favor of any such alteration to the
Constitution. Like many Conservative Republicans, Aldrich was too much of a
friend to big business to believe taxing their dividends to be in the least bit
desirable. But what the Senator from Rhode Island was betting on was that the
amendment would never be ratified. He could stomach – and would stomach – an
excise tax on corporate incomes, but he would only vote for Senator Brown’s
beloved amendment because he believed it was doomed to failure. On July 12th,
1909, this wager was put to the test, with a unanimous affirmation in the
Senate and a vote of 318-14 in the House The progressive Republicans came
around, conservative Republicans held firm, populist Democrats jumped at the
opportunity, and protectionist Democrats voted their interest. Nearly everyone,
it seemed, had got what they wanted. Now it fell to the states to prove Senator
Aldrich right or wrong.
Obviously, given that the 16th
Amendment is what it is, Senator Aldrich was wrong. Not only were state
legislatures in the South and West already inclined to support any such
measures as would obviate the need for the punishing federal tariffs which
their primarily agrarian inhabitants actively struggled to pay, but a sharp
rise in commodity prices that had begun in the late 1890s also primed states in
the Midwest and even the Northeast to respond favorably as well. In addition,
there also existed an increasingly influential segment of the Republican Party
inclined to view an undifferentiated federal income tax as an essential
ingredient in the national program that they envisioned. Described by faction
leader and former President Theodore Roosevelt in a speech in 1910 as the “New
Nationalism,” this program included the creation of a national health service,
social insurance, farm relief, and worker’s compensation, all of which was to
be accompanied by a general strengthening of the American military with an
emphasis on protecting the American merchant fleet. Absent some means of
funding such measures, of course, any one of them might have proven to be
ruinously expensive. In consequence, Roosevelt Republicans were also strongly
in favor of a robust regime of inheritance taxes and federal income taxes by
which their vision of a new America for the 20th century might be
placed on a stable footing. In light of the support increasingly enjoyed by the
likes of Roosevelt – whose popularity grew in proportion as that of his
hand-picked successor, Taft, waned – the only group left inclined to vote
against ratifying Senator Brown’s amendment were diehard conservative
Republicans like Senator Aldrich and his supporters. And as 1909 progressed
through to 1913, this faction’s influence steadily evaporated.
The actual progress of ratification makes
for a rather interesting tale. In the first year after the amendment’s
approval, from August of 1909 to August of 1910, only nine states saw their way
clear to providing their affirmation. But among that small number were exactly
the states one would expect to find at this early stage: Alabama, Kentucky,
South Carolina, Illinois, Mississippi, Oklahoma, Maryland, Georgia, and Texas.
All but Illinois were located in the South, and all were primarily agrarian in
terms of their economy. In light of their aforementioned antipathy towards the
continued imposition of federal tariffs, their support for a federal income tax
was more or less a given. The next stage in the ratification process took place
between January of 1911 and July of that same year, during which time no fewer than
twenty-two states added their own affirmations to the record. Among these
twenty-two were seven from the West – Idaho, Oregon, Washington, Montana,
California, Nevada, and Colorado – ten from the Midwest – Ohio, Indiana, South
Dakota, Nebraska, North Dakota, Michigan, Iowa, Kansas, Missouri, and Wisconsin
– three from the South – North Carolina, Tennessee, and Arkansas – and one –
New York – from the Northeast. Again, most of the enthusiasm seemed to come
from regions of the country most likely – due to the nature of the local
economy – to favor a shift from taxes on commodities to taxes on incomes, with
only one state from the region which benefitted from a reliance on tariffs
chiming in at the very end.
The next five states to ratify the
amendment were also something of a mixed bag. There was Arizona, in the
Southwest, which had only just become a state and was dominated by the
Democratic Party; Minnesota, in the Midwest, which was deeply agrarian in its
politics; Louisiana, in the South, about which much the same could be said;
West Virginia, in the Southeast, where the mining industry was king; and
Delaware, in the Northeast, which was the odd man out. Delaware being the 36th
state to vote in favor of ratification, the process was officially completed on
February 3rd, 1913. Over the next several months, the states that
followed were similarly telling. New Mexico and Wyoming were very much western
states, the former of which had only acceded to the union in January of 1912,
and New Jersey, Vermont, Massachusetts, and New Hampshire were all firmly in
the Northeast. Connecticut and Rhode Island, it bears noting, each voted to
reject the amendment, while the state of Pennsylvania never bothered to even
consider it. Given that all of these Northeastern states benefited from a
reliance on federal tariffs over federal excises, such a result was rather to
be expected.
All the same, it is interesting to note
that Roosevelt’s native New York, though home to some of the wealthiest
individuals and corporations in the country, opted to ratify the amendment relatively
early in the process, and that the state which carried the amendment across the
line, Delaware, was also located in the Northeast. These two ratifications –
along with those of New Jersey, Vermont, Massachusetts, and New Hampshire –
would seem to speak to the degree to which the tax debate in Congress which had
given rise to both the Payne-Aldrich Tariff and the 16th Amendment succeeded
in fracturing the contemporary Republican Party. Whereas, under the leadership of
President William McKinley in the late 1890s, Republicans had been so
supportive of protectionism that they approved the Dingley Tariff (1897), one
of the highest and longest lasting in the history of the United States, the influence
of William Howard Taft proved insufficient to either assuage the progressives
in his party or elicit compromise on the part of the conservatives. Indeed, his
stewardship of the party proved so divisive – or else the tensions which
McKinley had managed to keep at a low simmer could no longer be prevented from finally
boiling over – that the Republican National Convention, held in the summer of
1912, quickly devolved into a series of complaints and recriminations on the
part of the progressive wing of the party and saw Taft ultimately gain the nomination
and Roosevelt decide to bolt. The subsequent formation of the Progressive Party
under Roosevelt’s leadership in turn resulted in the incumbent Taft finishing
in third place in the Election of 1912, Roosevelt finishing in second, and Democrat
Woodrow Wilson coming in first.
But this is all rather beside the point, fascinating
though it may be in its own right. What matters, under the circumstances, is
what the proposal, approval, and successful ratification of the 16th
Amendment says about its fundamental character. Was it mainly a popular
initiative, an institutional reform, or something in between? In light of both
the nature of the policy which the amendment sought to empower and the
political machinations which resulted in its ultimate approval by Congress, the
latter of these characterizations would seem to be the most apt. There can be
no denying, circa 1909, that the concept of a federal income tax had more than
its share of popular support. As aforementioned, farmers and laborers in the
South, West, and Midwest increasingly struggled under the weight of federal
tariffs over the course of the 1890s and 1900s whose burden Northeastern
industrialists were able to shoulder with relative ease. Senators representing
the former regions accordingly had every reason – inasmuch as the legislators
who appointed them had every reason – to support such measures as would offer
relief to their constituents by shifting the nation’s tax burden to those most
able to pay it.
All that being said, the story of precisely
how the 16th Amendment made it out of Congress in the first place –
and the pace and cadence of its eventual ratification – speak to an a
substantially different line of causation. Senator Norris Brown, the initial
sponsor of the amendment, no doubt acted when and how he did because he felt he
had the backing of the newly inaugurated President Taft and because he believed
that Taft broadly shared his progressive political principles. And Senator
Nelson Aldrich, whose support inarguably made the amendment’s approval possible,
most assuredly acted as he did only in order to allay a major division in his
party and to secure the passage of his preferred version of the tariff bill
then under discussion in Congress. That his strategy failed on both counts would
seem to be a testament both to the depth of the cleavage then tearing the
Republican Party apart and to the degree to which a federal income tax
represented a policy with national appeal. To no small extent, it must be said,
state legislatures acted as they did during the ratification process because
the members thereof understood that providing tax relief to the constituents
was bound to pay electoral dividends. But there was also doubtless a
significant degree of party politicking wrapped up in which states voted, and
when, and how.
The ratification of the 16th
Amendment, recall, took place at the same time as the two major parties were readying
themselves to take part in the Election of 1912. And in terms of the Republicans
in particular, it took place over a period that witnessed their continued
splintering and final division into two parties. In consequence, while Republican
state legislators were then in the midst of considering the aforementioned amendment,
they were also simultaneously undertaking to hold primaries and assign
delegates for the purpose of choosing their party’s eventual nominee for
President. Given that Roosevelt’s New Nationalism program – discussed above –
held up the imposition of federal income taxes as key to its eventual success,
and given that President Taft received most of his support from regions of the country
where conservative Republicans on the model of Senator Aldrich held sway, it
would seem fairly reasonable to assume that either ratifying or rejecting the
amendment in question became a part of how the various state Republican parties
– where said parties were in control of the state legislature – asserted their
factional standing as the Election of 1912 drew ever closer. Were these
Republicans legislators entirely unmoved by the financial travails of their
constituents or their own desire for reelection? Of course not. But with a
presidential contest in the offing and their party in the process of a very
messy ideological realignment, the Republicans who then controlled the various
state assemblies had things to consider beyond simply pleasing the voters. The
16th Amendment, therefore, like so many of its predecessors, would seem
best characterized as the product of both popular and institutional support.
No comments:
Post a Comment