A further reason
Richard Price had heard advanced for the rightness of Britain’s dominance
vis-à-vis the Thirteen Colonies, he next affirmed, was the apparent, “Superiority of the British State.” In
response to such vague rationale, the author of Observations was quite reasonably given to ask, “What gives us our
superiority?–Is it our Wealth? […] Is
it the number of our people? […] Is
it our knowledge and virtue?” To each
of these he answered in the negative, thus dismissing “superiority” as a
possible criterion for political domination as well as exposing some degree of
his own and his countrymen’s cultural and philosophical biases. To the question
of wealth, for instance, Price responded that, “This never confers real
dignity. On the contrary: Its effect is always to debase, intoxicate, and
corrupt.” It would not be difficult to imagine that many of Price’s countrymen
indeed thought that wealth was a source of dignity, and that the tremendous
wealth collectively possessed by the British people at the end of the 18th
century did rightly entitle them to claim a measure of functional superiority
over their American counterparts. Given to exaggeration though the author of Observations might have been – especially
when it came to the aspects of contemporary British society he found
distasteful – banking, investing, stock-jobbing, and various other “new money”
ventures really were in the midst of transforming the British state. As wealth
became concentrated in the hands of those who in a previous era would not have
possessed much, if any, social capital, values began to shift as money became
revered nearly as much as landed title.
As Price noted,
however, such vast accumulations of wealth were not solely a source of dignity
and respect. Money makes people question their convictions, and in larger sums
has an even greater effect. The wealth generated by Britain’s turn towards
national banking, mercantilism, and territorial expansion was accordingly bound
to have a proportionate effect on the integrity of that nation’s culture and
institutions. Positions of power changed hands, favors were trades, bribes made
and received. Such things seem to be inevitable in any sufficiently complex
socio-political framework, and become more pronounced as more money and more
power become available. Individuals have been known to resist, of course, and
steps have certainly been taken historically by whole cultures and governments
to negate the influence of excess wealth on the direction of public affairs.
For this reason Price’s claim that the only effect of wealth “Is always to
debase, intoxicate, and corrupt” represents something of an overstatement. That
being said, it is very much in keeping with his aforementioned affinity for the
reformist ideology of the Country Party and its successors. Having become
convinced that any corruption represented an indelible stain on the national
soul, and that what corruption Britain had theretofore experienced was the
result of the conspiratorial machinations of a moneyed and connected elite,
Price would naturally have been among the first to claim that wealth could
never entitle a single person – let alone an entire nation – to unquestioned
supremacy over their fellow man.
To the question of
population, Price again answered in a way that perhaps implies more than it
plainly states. “The Colonies,” he declared, “Will soon be equal to us in
number.” While in retrospect it may seem a rather silly thing for one nation to
claim a right of superiority over another based on a difference in population,
the implication is perhaps not so difficult to grasp. One must assume, of
course, that Price wasn’t misrepresenting his countrymen in thus describing
their rationale. That he appeared not to question the premise of the question
would seem to indicate that he was not. Bearing this in mind, it would appear
likely that both Price and those of his fellow Britons he had set himself
against were given to thinking of the relationship between different
communities of people along roughly democratic lines. In Parliament, after all,
MPs were elected to serve their constituents by a majority vote, and these
representatives in turn approved legislation by the very same logic. While
there existed in 1776 no assembly in which the combined representatives of
Britain and America sat, it would nevertheless have been far from unnatural for
a contemporary British citizen to envision the relationship between their own
nation and its American dependencies according to much the same logic. If there
were simply more people in Britain than America, why should not the intercourse
between them proceed in the same manner as a debate in Parliament? Why
shouldn’t Britain, representing the greater share of humanity, see its will
triumphant over that of America? It was only logical, after all, whether a vote
could actually be taken or not.
In truth, it’s rather curious that Price
appeared to grant this premise at all. Sanguine though he appeared to be
towards the principle of majority rule – there being no evidence to suggest
that he was not – he had also made it fairly clear within the text of his Observations that he believed there was
a crucial difference between the logic of relations among communities within a
given state and the logic of relations among a group of separate states. The
majority of the representatives sitting in a legislature – even if they
represented only fifty-one percent of those present – had every right to
determine which laws were to be put in place effecting one hundred percent of
the population because every member of the society to be effected – in theory,
at least – possessed some degree of input into the relevant process. Such a
deliberative apparatus conversely did not exist between two sovereign,
independent states. Within the context of the Anglo-America relationship, for
example, power was the deciding factor in terms of which policies were enacted
and which were not. Great Britain – circa 1776 – was militarily and
economically more powerful than even a united America, thereby allowing it to
effectively dictate what would and would not come to pass between them. That
this power had nothing to do – or very little to do – with population should be
exceptionally obvious. Certainly there were more people living in Britain at
that time than lived in America, but that fact had no effect whatsoever upon
how decisions were made. Parliament decided what was to become of America
without paying any heed – or being legally obligated to pay any heed – to the
stated desires of the inhabitants of British America. A sudden increase in the
American population would accordingly have made no difference to this state of
affairs. Inclined though certain British people made have been – quite possibly
including Price himself – to think about public policy in terms of majority
rule, therefore, the concept had no application whatsoever within the context
of the Anglo-American relationship.
All the same – and for whatever reason –
Price did engage with the idea. And his contention, as cited above, was that,
“The Colonies will soon be equal to us in number.” Bearing in mind that the
word “soon” can be variously interpreted to mean anything between “any minute
now” and “within the next century,” Price might fairly be said to have been
right. At the time of its first official census in 1800, the United Kingdom of
Great Britain and Ireland contained something on the order of fifteen million
people. The United States of America, in that same year conducting its second
decennial census, was conversely home to slightly less than five and a half
million. Twenty-five years, it would seem, was not enough time for Price’s
prediction to come true. If one were to press forward, however, though the
1810s, 20s, 30, 40s, and 50s, the corresponding population data for 1860 appears
to bear out its validity. At that point the population of the United Kingdom
had reached a figure just shy of twenty-nine million. The United States, by
comparison, was sitting at a total of thirty-one million. Without going into
how this came to be – a discussion having to do mainly with the Industrial
Revolution, the aftermath of the Napoleonic Wars in Europe, and the resulting
explosion of European migration to America – it will here accordingly suffice
to observe that Price was ultimately proven correct within about ninety years
of his having made the claim in question.
Whether this fact has very much at all to
do with the argument he was attempting to advance within the text of his Observations – i.e. that Britain had no
inherent right to declare itself the master of America – is eminently debatable.
Again, mere population seemed to have very little connection to the fundamental
point he was trying to make. That being said, Price’s claim was rhetorically an
effective one. In answer to the hypothetical assertion that Britain deserved to
dictate to America because the residents of the latter outnumbered those of the
former, Price declared that this would soon no longer be the case. While he was
proven right within the span of a century, there was naturally no way for him –
or anyone else, for that matter – to confirm this fact. Then again, there was
also no way for a prospective opponent to dismiss it. Therein, arguably, lay
its genius. By offering an effectively un-confirmable counter to a claim with
which he disagreed, Price essentially neutralized it. No one could confirm in
1776 that the American population would one day meet and eclipse that of
Britain. Nor could they deny it, however, beyond the shadow of a doubt. That
being the case, it would surely have seemed foolish to the supporter of British
supremacy to base their claim upon such an uncertain principle. Consider, for
example, the likely result of a sudden famine in Britain. Millions might have
perished, and as many might have migrated to America. Within ten years, or
twenty, or thirty, Britain might accordingly have no longer possessed the
larger share of the empire’s population. And what then of British claims of
superiority? How then could anyone justify a smaller nation holding authority
over a larger one? Population, in short, could not be taken a basis of
argument. It could change too suddenly, too quickly. It was not solid. It could
not be depended on.
This may well have been exactly the point
that Price was trying to make. Again, it’s not clear why he felt the need to
engage with the notion of demographic superiority when his fundamental point
had been and would be better made by other means. But so long as he did choose
to address the argument that Britain somehow deserved to rule over America
because there were more British people than there were Americans, the
implications of his counterargument were nonetheless highly significant. Numbers,
in the context of national sovereignty, made no difference to whether a nation
could govern itself or not, or whether it could govern another nation or not.
Self-government was not a prize a state only gained only after breaking a given
demographic threshold, nor was it something that could be accumulated in excess
and exerted by one state upon another. Sovereignty was inherent, fundamental,
and immutable, having nothing to do with population, wealth, or power and
everything to do with the humanity, liberty, and dignity of the individual. It
could be delegated, channelled, and even constrained by mutual consent. But it
could not be taken away from one nation because another claimed to have more of
something than its counterpart.
Not only would it have been fundamentally
inhuman to accordingly treat the right of self-government like some kind of
reward, but it would very shortly prove a very foolish basis upon which to
justify one’s authority. Because population, just like wealth, military power,
and cultural distinction, ebbs and flows according to trends predictable and
unpredictable, artificial and naturally occurring. Rooting the authority of
one’s nation – particularly in terms of its right to hold sway over other
nations – in the possession of an advantage in any of these categories would
therefore inevitably open one up to being conquered, subsumed, or overawed
whenever fate happened to dictate a sudden change in material circumstances.
Not only would this seem to present an intolerable state of affairs – i.e.
nations constantly shifting between ruling others and being ruled – but it
would once again appear to wholly discount the fundamental value of the human
spirit. People, Price had earlier affirmed in the text of his Observations, were not livestock to be
manhandled as those who sought to benefit from their existence saw fit. On the
contrary, they were thinking, feeling beings to whom a quantity of basic
respect was owed and from whose consent all forms of government necessarily
derived.
The supposed “knowledge and virtue” of the
British people was likewise dismissed by Price as being for the most part
illusory. Britain may well have been able to boast of the keen minds and noble
hearts among its many millions, but this hardly made it exceptional among
nations. Indeed, Price avowed, the inhabitants of America, “Are probably equally knowing, and more virtuous. There are names among
them that will not stoop to any names among the philosophers and politicians of
this island.” As with the issue of population cited above, a claim such as this
could not easily be confirmed. Certainly there were a handful of prominent
Americans whose efforts in their chosen fields had indeed made them famous beyond
their native environs. There were painters, for example, like John Singleton
Copley (1738-1815) and Benjamin West (1738-1820), both of whom migrated to Britain
in the latter half of the 18th century in pursuit of the kind of
exposure and patronage the colonies simply could not supply. West in particular
met with great success, his work garnering him the sobriquet of “the American
Raphael” among the British public. He was later appointed president of the
Royal Academy of Arts in 1792. Theologians were also among those Americans
whose reputations managed the long Atlantic crossing. Jonathan Edwards
(1703-1758) was undoubtedly the most prominent of these, being one of the
principal contributors to the trans-Atlantic religious revival that swept
across the British Empire in the 1730s, 40s, and 50s – the so-called “First
Great Awakening” – an ardent ally of reformist English preachers like George
Whitefield (1714-1770), and the author of numerous books, pamphlets, and
sermons that are in some cases still read today by British and American
Evangelical Christians.
Benjamin Franklin (1706-1790), of course,
was without a doubt the most famous American of the pre-Revolutionary era, both
among his countrymen in the colonies and the wider British public. A printer,
writer, scientist, inventor, philosopher, and satirist, Franklin crossed the
Atlantic numerous times over the course of his long life, becoming variously a
public intellectual and man of letters in his adopted home city of
Philadelphia, a diplomat and statesmen in the Court at Westminster, an early
patron and member of the Royal Society of Arts in London, and pioneering
natural philosopher with honorary doctorates from St. Andrews and Oxford
universities. He was also a friend and contemporary of Price himself, alongside
numerous other reformers, intellectuals, artists, scientists, and statesmen
then living and working in late 18th century Britain. In consequence
of these many and varied accomplishments and connections, Franklin was for many
contemporary British citizens the only American they could easily name. That he
was also one of the most prominent public figures of the era – a kind of 18th
century celebrity, if you will – doubtless lends some credence to Price’s
aforementioned claim. There may not have been very many Americans in the 1770s
whose talents were being celebrated on both sides of the Atlantic, but those
few who managed to achieve this pinnacle of success certainly spoke well of the
abilities of their fellow countrymen. West, Edwards, and Franklin were among
some of the most successful and most acclaimed in their respected fields, to
the point that their parochial origins ceased to stand in the way of their
being embraced by the mainstream of contemporary British society.
Whether this could be said to validate
Price’s claim of Americans being “equally knowing” when compared to their
British counterparts remains an open question, however. After all, how does one
measure the relative possession of knowledge or skill? Great Britain – as
mentioned at length above – possessed the larger population circa 1776,
therefore almost certainly guaranteeing that the number of particularly intelligent,
knowledgeable, or accomplished individuals living therein was bound to be
greater than comparatively minuscule America could hope to boast. Did that mean
that Britain was the more knowledgeable nation? Or were such things best
measured on a per capita basis? That is to say, was it valid to claim – with
the aforementioned American luminaries as examples – that the most intelligent
Americans were the equals of the most intelligent Britons? There were not –
perhaps could never be – easy answers to these questions. All the same, Price
was at the very least correct in asserting that Americans, as a people, were
not less intellectually capable, artistically inclined, or morally upstanding
than their British equivalents.
This once again seemed not to be the point, however. Proud though contemporary Americans had
every right to be of the accomplishments of their various prominent countrymen,
these accomplishments bore no relationship at all to their possession of
certain fundamental liberties. Rather, as Price himself asserted in his Observations, they derived their
entitlement to free worship, free movement, free property, and free government
simply from their status as members of the human race. Relative wealth did not
affect this, any more than did physical power, fame, knowledge, or numbers.
People were free, he affirmed, by nature, and when they formed communities,
those communities were free. And then those communities sought to administer
themselves, the resulting governments were free. All derived from the
fundamental autonomy of the individual, and all ceased to function if that
autonomy was curtailed. Not only was this fairer than assigning sovereignty
only to those whose communities could boast the smartest, strongest, ablest
members, but it was infinitely more sensible. Late 18th century
Britain had certainly given rise to more than its share of intellectual and
artistic luminaries – to the point that it could fairly be said to dominate the
Anglo-American public discourse – but there was simply no way to guarantee that
this would always be the case. Consequent to any number of factors, America
might suddenly experience a tremendous and unprecedented explosion of talent
and expression in the arts, sciences, and humanities, thus drastically shifting
the cultural balance in its favor vis-à-vis its nominal colonial master. What
then? Should anyone living in the contemporary Anglo-American world thereafter
expect Parliament to acquiesce to the dictates of the united colonies? Price’s
answer – notwithstanding his evident willingness to engage with the basic
premise – would almost certainly have been that such thinking was plainly
ridiculous. The British and American peoples were each sovereign in and of
themselves, regardless of how wealthy, or numerous, of intelligent they
happened to be. This was only proper, only just, only right.
No comments:
Post a Comment