Certain of the
provisions contained within the text of the Articles of Confederation are less
oblique than those cited previously in terms of the authority they appear to
confer upon the resulting national government. In some instances, it seemed,
Dickinson and his committee were more comfortable at least appearing to assert
national prerogatives than was generally the case. As to the financial standing
of the United States of America, for example, the framers of the Articles seemed
quite confident – as per the text of Article VIII – that all expenses to be
incurred by the union of states, “Allowed by the United States in Congress
assembled, shall be defrayed out of a common treasury, which shall be supplied
by the several States in proportion to the value of all land within each state
[.]” This phrasing appears to admit of little ambiguity: there was to be a
treasury, doubtless administered by Congress, to be supplied collectively by
the states and to serve their common needs. Not only does this appear a fairly
logical consideration – there being any number of potential projects or
policies from which every state could benefit and for which no one state ought
to bear the cost – but it very much accords with what is by now the expected
financial relationship between the government of the United States and its many
millions of constituents.
This evident sense
of familiarity, however, might easily obscure a lack of any relevant mechanism
of enforcement. Whereas the present government of the United States has any
number of means at its disposal by which it might seek to ensure the payment of
the taxes it levies upon individuals or corporations, the Articles of
Confederation provided almost no method, process, or procedure through which
the administration it described could seek to collect upon the requisitions it
made of the states. Indeed, the United States in Congress Assembled – a phrase
used more than once in the text of the Articles as the formal name of the
government of the American union – seemed almost wholly incapable of enforcing
its will upon the states in any context, let alone the exceptionally sensitive
area of taxation. In consequence, the text of Article VIII – along with several
other provisions that appear unequivocal but which in practice were relatively
meaningless – seems to present something of a paradox. Congress, it appeared,
was intended to administer a common treasury as a means of defraying the shared
expenses of the states, and accordingly to collect such funds from the states
as deemed necessary for the maintenance thereof, at the same time that it was
almost wholly restrained from coercing the states to do anything at all.
Bizarre though this construction may appear – and indeed, as it may be – it
would not appear particularly out of step with the essential character of the
Articles, the resulting national government, or the men responsible for the
creation thereof.
If the framers of
the Articles were nothing else – if they were not competent, if they were not
insightful, if they were not up to the task of creating an effective national
government – they were most definitely optimistic as to the future prospects of
the United States of America. Their belief in the inevitability of the nation’s
territorial expansion (see Articles IX and XI) speaks to this conviction quite
clearly, as do their apparent efforts to foster the legal, commercial, and
cultural integration of the various states (see Article IV). This sense of
confidence might well have allowed the authors of the Articles to see beyond
the admittedly strained material circumstances of the contemporary moment –
i.e. a war with the most powerful empire in the history of the world that had
yet to turn in favor of Congress – and provide tools and guidance by which the
American people could succeed in meeting the obstacles and the opportunities
their collective future yet held. This lofty and far-reaching perspective was
not, however, without its drawbacks. While Dickinson and his committee
possessed vision enough to foresee the need for a common purse – or more
broadly for a means by which the states might seek to undertake shared
endeavors in time of peace – they evidently could not bring themselves to in
any way give Congress the power to collect the money they envisioned it someday
disbursing. That they did nothing to address the resulting contradiction –
either by removing any mention of a common treasury or providing some means by
which needed funds might be collected – in turn represents perhaps their
greatest failure. By leaving in place the various expressions of their optimism
without also supplying the appropriate mechanisms that might have seen that
optimism fulfilled, the framers of the Articles created a national government
for the American union that was arguably doomed to dysfunction.
Consider, by way
of evidence, several more lines of the text of Article VIII. As mentioned above,
this section was particularly concerned with providing for the maintenance of a
shared treasury by and for the United States of America. As to the means by
which that treasury was to be sustained, all value for the purpose of taxation,
it was stated, “Shall be estimated according to such mode as the United States
in Congress assembled, shall from time to time direct and appoint.” While, on
its surface, this would seem a fairly straightforward and easily-observed
directive, the clause which immediately followed portended significant
complications. “The taxes for paying that proportion,” it read, “shall be laid
and levied by the authority and direction of the legislatures of the several
States [.]” In consequence, while Congress was responsible for assessing the
value of all property within the states for the purpose of taking receipt of
the proportion each state owed to the national treasury, only the states could
levy and collect the resulting taxes. Faithful though this arrangement may have
been to the principle of delegating taxing authority to the body in which the
taxed are directly represented – a conviction for which, among others, many
Americans were lately demonstrating their willingness to fight and die – it
could not have but begged a number of uncomfortable questions. What would have
been the result, for example, if Congress requested a payment for which a given
state(s) declined to generate revenue? Likewise, what would occur in the event
that Congress and a given state(s) disagreed as to the value of a particular
piece of property? The text of the Articles could provide no solutions to these
kinds of difficulties, chiefly because the authors of the same were similarly
bereft of any means to reconcile their vision with their principles.
Clauses contained in Article IX and Article
XIII would appear to present similar examples of powers or characteristics
being attributed to the government of the United States absent the accompanying
mechanisms for their practical realization. The former, while seeking to
describe the means by which Congress might occasionally be forced to request
the service of military forces raised by the states, notably included the
specific declaration that these selfsame requisitions, “Shall be binding, and
thereupon the legislature of each State shall appoint the regimental officers,
raise the men and clothe, arm and equip them in a soldier-like manner, at the
expense of the United States [.]” In the context of 18th and 19th
century American history, this would seem a fairly reasonable directive for
Congress to have at its disposal. As early as 1794, during a major anti-tax
protest in Western Pennsylvania commonly known as the Whiskey Rebellion, the
government of the United States had reason to summon militia forces from a
number of states for the purpose of enforcing federal law. A more famous – and
perhaps more consequential – instance of this same prerogative being invoked
occurred in May, 1861 when President Abraham Lincoln (1809-1865), confronted by
a Southern rebellion, requested the service of nearly 120,000 volunteer
militiamen from the states that continued to recognize the authority of the
federal government. In both instances, the justification for Congress and the
President issuing the relevant orders was to be found in Article I, Section 8
of the Constitution. “Congress shall have the power,” the appropriate passage
declares, “To provide for calling forth the Militia to execute the Laws of the
Union, suppress Insurrections and repel Invasions [.]” And while this specific
provision – or indeed any of those detailed in Section 8 – was not accompanied
by language detailing the means by which Congress might ensure obedience in
seeing the relevant commands carried out, the Constitution as a whole provides
a number of mechanisms by which the government of the United States might
either punish or coerce the states in the event of noncompliance.
It should by now be taken as a given that
the Articles of Confederation contained no such means of ensuring submission to
its directives. Under the auspices of the resulting national government,
Congress could not easily withhold or make an incentive out of grants from the common
treasury – for which it had no reliable means to collect funds to begin with –
assert its control over the relevant state militia – the raising and staffing
of which fell to the various states legislatures – or threaten to bring suit
against the state in question in a federal court of law – made impossible by
the fact that there were no federal courts under the terms of the Articles. For
Dickinson and his committee to inscribe into the text of the first governing
charter of the American union that all military requisitions made by Congress
of the states “shall be binding” was therefore in effect to say nothing at all
of substance. Practically speaking, if the national government described by the
Articles asked, say, the state of Virginia to supply two militia regiments for
the purpose of putting down a rebellion, countering an invasion, or taking part
in a punitive expedition into a neighboring territory, the choice of doing so
or not would lie entirely with the state in question. In this hypothetical scenario,
the government of Virginia could agree to fulfil the requisition, having
recognized that the resolution desired by Congress was likely to serve its
interests as well, or it could refuse to do so, having decided that its
resources were best put to use elsewhere. The national government would have no
practical means to either encourage one outcome or punish the other, the cited
text of Article IX notwithstanding.
The first paragraph of the thirteenth and
last of the Articles of Confederation contains perhaps the most ambitious of
all declarations contained therein as to the ability of the resulting national
government to assert itself upon the states. “Every state,” the passage in
question asserts,
Shall abide
by the determination of the United States in Congress assembled, on all
questions which by this confederation are submitted to them. And the Articles
of this Confederation shall be inviolably observed by every State, and the
Union shall be perpetual [.]
Formalistic
language aside, the basic premise of this provision is that the various states
were to be bound by the decisions rendered by Congress, that the text of the
Articles was to be similarly binding, and that no state was to reserve to
itself the right or the means of withdrawing from the union. Ignoring for the
moment the cited text of Article II – whereby the states were to retain their
“sovereignty, freedom, and independence” – Article XIII would thereby appear to
imply that Dickinson and his committee envisioned membership in the American
union as having a restrictive effect upon the discretion of the states. If, for
example, Congress issued a directive which the government of a given state
disagreed with, a strict adherence to the text of Article XIII would seem to
offer little choice but acquiescence. Likewise, if a state government
determined, after a period of years, that continued membership in the American
union no longer aligned with the best interests of its constituents, Article
XIII would seem to wholly preclude said government ever acting upon its desire
for separation. For a document that opened with an assertion of the continued
autonomy of the parties it sought to effect, these would seem to be wholly
contradictory limitations.
In practice, of course, there was nothing
for the states to fear in the text of Article XIII. Lacking virtually any means
by which to penalize the denial of its directives, Congress could no more
ensure the inviolable observation of either its authority or the core
provisions of the Articles than it could declare the Moon to be the fourteenth
state in the union. Individual states could – and in practice, often did –
ignore “the determination of the United States in Congress assembled” with
impunity, pursue whatever course of action they felt would best serve their
needs, and generally comport themselves as though no national government
existed at all. As to secession, while it did not occur – or even realistically
threaten to occur – during the lifetime of the United States government under
the Articles, there was little in the structure of the confederation or the
mechanisms at its disposal to dissuade states from pursuing such a course. In
the event that, prompted by the determination of the government of a given
state to separate itself from the American union, Congress called upon the
remaining states to provide the military force necessary to prevent the
partition from occurring, the result would surely have been yet another
intractable impasse. For as functionally incapable as the national government
under the Articles would have been of preventing a state from leaving the
union, so too would it have been at a loss to coerce the remaining states into
turning their arms upon their fellow Americans.
Granted, this kind of scenario was almost
certainly the last thing that Dickinson and his committee envisioned when they
crafted the text of Article XIII. No doubt they indeed desired for the union of
American states to be perpetual, harmonious, and effective, but never at the
cost of limiting freedom or threatening civil war. Recognizing the sovereignty
of the states and of their citizens appeared always to have been foremost in
their minds as they set to work on the various clauses and provisions that came
to comprise the Articles of Confederation. Rather than command the obedience of
the states, it seemed, as a matter of law, the United States in Congress
Assembled was ostensibly intended to encourage loyalty based on its ability to
offer the states a forum for collective action and its inability to infringe
upon their rights as sovereign entities. Pleasing though this might have been
to contemporary philosophical sensibilities, however, it represented an
extremely flimsy basis on which to erect a functioning government. This becomes
particularly obvious when one considers the sheer number of contradictions or
loose ends embedded in the relevant text. Empowered to administer a shared
treasury, make military requisitions of the states, and enjoin continued
adherence to and membership in the American union, Congress wholly lacked the
means by which it could achieve any of these outcomes. It could not demand of
the states, or direct them, or order them. Rather, it could do no more than
ask. In this, the fault seems once again to lie with the framers for failing to
restrain themselves from giving the national government statutory authority in
areas they were simultaneously unwilling to vest it with practical power.
In was as if, caught between erecting a government that fostered and pursued clear national
priorities and one that merely facilitated reasonably harmonious relations
among the states, the framers of the Articles leaned heavily towards the latter
without completely abandoning their interest in the former. Doubtless it would
have been simpler if they had given up any hope that the United States of
America would become a nation in and of itself – that there would come to exist
something like a national will in which every state and every citizen could
identify their respective interests. Instead, faced with either eliminating any
references to national prerogatives or providing the means that might have seen
them accomplished, Dickinson and his committee seemed to have instead thrown up
their hands and left things standing in some awkward middle ground as though the
ability of Congress to function as the Articles described would materialize via
some unknown alchemical process. The result was a truly chimerical creation
whose lack of internal consistency invited dysfunction and malaise. Certainly
it aligned with the ideological proclivities of the Continental Congress and
the majority of their supporters in the states – unsettled as they were by the
idea of giving rise to an institution powerful enough to command the states to
action – to so limit the authority of the first permanent national government
in Anglo-American history. But providing some degree of philosophical
reassurance may have been all that it could accomplish of its own accord and on
its own merits, so beholden was resulting regime to the inclinations of the
states.